Difference between revisions of "Tax Avoidance"

From TFD Online 2024-25
Jump to: navigation, search
(Created page with "''Users may contribute to the text. If you see anything that needs correcting or expanding, please click on the edit link and make the corrections. A copy of the next ed...")
 
(Tax avoidance: Introduction)
Line 6: Line 6:
  
  
Tax avoidance is as old as taxation itself;<ref>For examples from 1798 and 1920, see "Tax Avoidance in 1798" <i>http://www.kessler.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2013/06/Tax-avoidance-criticism-in-1798.pdf</i> and "Vestey: Royal Commission evidence and ensuing debate"
+
Tax avoidance is as old as taxation itself;<ref>For examples from 1798 and 1920, see "Tax Avoidance in 1798" :<i>http://www.kessler.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2013/06/Tax-avoidance-criticism-in-1798.pdf</i> and "Vestey: Royal Commission evidence and ensuing debate"
  
<i>http://www.kessler.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2013/07/Vestey_Royal_Commission_evidence_and_ensuing_debate.pdf</i>.</ref> but the topic has taken prominence over the last few years, with extensive attention from parliament and the media.<ref>It is interesting to speculate why that has been the case. I think the reasons lie more in the realm of politics and sociology than tax law and practice.  The Public Accounts Committee, and some effective pressure groups, have clearly contributed but given the pressure on the front page, why has their work received so enthusiastic a reception?  The 2008 financial crisis and climate of austerity may be a factor.</ref>
+
:<i>http://www.kessler.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2013/07/Vestey_Royal_Commission_evidence_and_ensuing_debate.pdf</i>.</ref> but the topic has taken prominence over the last few years, with extensive attention from parliament and the media.<ref>It is interesting to speculate why that has been the case. I think the reasons lie more in the realm of politics and sociology than tax law and practice.  The Public Accounts Committee, and some effective pressure groups, have clearly contributed but given the pressure on the front page, why has their work received so enthusiastic a reception?  The 2008 financial crisis and climate of austerity may be a factor.</ref>
  
The topic impinges on many aspects of this book, but it is best to consider it as a subject and in a chapter of its own.
+
The subject impinges on many aspects of this book, but it is best to consider it as a topic and in a chapter of its own.
  
 
The title of this chapter derives from the splendid admonition of David Cameron:
 
The title of this chapter derives from the splendid admonition of David Cameron:

Revision as of 14:35, 27 November 2017

Users may contribute to the text. If you see anything that needs correcting or expanding, please click on the edit link and make the corrections. A copy of the next edition of the book will be given to the user who makes the most edits. User contributions are reviewed by Oliver Marre.


Tax avoidance: Introduction

Tax avoidance is as old as taxation itself;[1] but the topic has taken prominence over the last few years, with extensive attention from parliament and the media.[2]

The subject impinges on many aspects of this book, but it is best to consider it as a topic and in a chapter of its own.

The title of this chapter derives from the splendid admonition of David Cameron:


Of course there is a difference between tax evasion and tax avoidance. Evasion is illegal. It can and should be subject to the full force of the criminal law.
But what about tax avoidance? Now of course there's nothing wrong with sensible tax planning and there are some things that governments want people to do that reduce tax bills, such as investing in a pension, a start up business or giving money to a charity. But there are some forms of avoidance that have become so aggressive that I think it is right to say these raise ethical issues, and it is time to call for more responsibility and for governments to act accordingly.
In the UK we've already committed hundreds of millions (?) into this effort, but acting alone has its limits. Clamp down in one country and the travelling caravan of lawyers, accountants and financial gurus will just move on elsewhere. ...
I believe in low taxes, that is why my government is cutting the top rate of income tax, we've cut corporation tax. [Delete - political].[3]
Individuals and businesses must pay their fair share. And businesses who think they can carry on dodging that fair share, or that they can keep on selling to the UK and setting up ever more complex tax arrangements abroad to squeeze their tax bills right down, well they need to wake up and smell the coffee, because the public who buy from them have had enough.[4]


All the main tropes of the political debate are in this passage:

(1) Everyone should pay a "fair share" of tax.

(2) Some taxpayers fail to do so due to tax avoidance.

(3) Tax avoidance is unethical, immoral or anti-social.

(4) Acknowledgement of the avoidance/evasion distinction;[5] but it does not contradict point (3). In the words of Margaret Hodge: "We're not accusing you of being illegal, we're accusing you of being immoral."

(5) Disparaging references to tax advisers.[6]


On the political left, the same points are made, but more stridently, and of course without David Cameron's approval of low taxes.

Need for analysis

This chapter draws on a paper published by the Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation, ("the OUCBT paper").[7] The OUCBT paper says:


The question is how to tackle the problems. This requires a clear analysis of their cause and differentiation between different causes. Labelling a whole range of quite different behaviours as "avoidance" without further differentiation is unhelpful. ...


Any differentiation requires terminology. As there is no agreed terminology,[8] it is best not to use any terms at all without some explanation of what is meant.


OUCBT categorisation

The OUCBT paper distinguishes:

(1) Ineffective avoidance (no tax saving if the law is correctly applied)

(2) Effective avoidance (tax saved by avoidance)

(3) Non-avoidance (little tax paid but not due to avoidance)[9]


These are essential distinctions if one is to identify the correct response to the problems:

(1) Ineffective avoidance may be countered by enforcement of the law.

(2) Effective avoidance can only be countered by changes in tax law.

(3) In cases of non-avoidance:

(a) It may be no change in tax law is appropriate.[10]
(b) If change is needed, the change is one of policy as well as of tax law; and the matter should be considered without the haste and moral outrage that effective avoidance tends to cause.

Tax practitioners classification

If one wishes to assess emotional and moral responses to avoidance, and actual or theoretical anti-avoidance rules, we need further vocabulary to discuss the range of tax-motivated behaviour.

We might cover the terrain in four categories:[11]


Uncontroversial tax planning Taking advantage of a tax relief in a manner everyone would accept as reasonable and indeed desirable. As this is at the bottom of the spectrum, it is easy to find clear examples: for instance, pension contributions, and moderate[12] charity giving.[13] This is so even though some care is often needed in order to maximise the relief, for instance, fixing contributions each year to below the cap for the relief, or fixing benefits within the permitted limits for gift aid.


Ordinary tax planning Using tax legislation in a way which some politicians and commentators do not like, but where the planning is ordinary in the sense that many people have done and continue to do it; it is obvious and foreseeable; the points probably came to the mind of those responsible for the legislation, or should have done, or there is no reason to think that parliament would have done anything different if it had considered the points. Ordinary tax planning is not contrary to the "intention of parliament" as that construct is normally understood.

Examples are:

(1) Advancing or delaying

(a) disposals for CGT purposes or
(b) bonuses or pension contributions for IT purposes

in anticipation of changes of rates or going non-resident.

(2) Transfer of family assets or business to a spouse to equalise income.

(3) Transfer to a company to reduce tax rates.

(4) Lifetime giving to avoid IHT.

(5) Going non-resident.

The term "tax mitigation" could be used to cover uncontroversial tax planning and ordinary tax planning.


Tax avoidance Something legal but contrary to the intention of parliament in the sense that had parliament thought about it, it would probably prevent the tax advantage. An example is the transfer of assets to a non-resident company where the transferor has power to enjoy.

Other possible examples are:

(1) The scheme in Furniss v Dawson.

(2) Temporary non-residence (if tax-driven).

However one might place these at the upper reaches of the ordinary tax planning spectrum.


Tax abuse Tax avoidance with aggravating features (typically, self-cancelling steps) that make it (more) unreasonable.[14] As this is at the top of the spectrum, it is easy to find clear examples: take the schemes in: Ramsay, Fitzwilliam, Astall and Mayes.


Thus this terminology raises three distinctions:

(1) Uncontroversial/ordinary tax planning

(2) Tax planning/avoidance

(3) Tax avoidance/abuse


Before considering whether these distinctions have, or should have, different consequences, it is important to note three difficulties which they entail:

(1) The demarcation problem Except at the extreme ends of the spectrum, the demarcation problem is intractable: the classification of specific examples (if it actually had to be decided) would give rise to endless disagreement (and has done so in the context of tax motive defences). There are two reasons for this:

(a) The distinctions rely on:
(i) imponderable hypothetical questions (what would parliament have done if it had noticed the issue?)
(ii) vague constructs ("the intention of parliament" and "the spirit of the legislation")
(iii) identifying tax policy (there may be no clear policy, or it may fluctuate).
(b) The four distinct categories attempt to impose an order on tax motivated behaviour which exhibits a scale of unreasonableness, without distinct divisions. It might be better to mark out a sliding scale from 1 to 10, recognising finer distinctions, but that would not help for practical purposes. It is often the case that experience is a continuum on which the law seeks to impose bipolar categories, but the difficulty in doing so here is greater than usual because the distinction is more imponderable.

(2) The tax-law knowledge problem Except for the extreme ends of the spectrum, (a small part of the field) a serious discussion of where any particular arrangement should be classified, or graded, can only be carried out by someone who understands the tax background. Few non-practitioners have much understanding. Journalists in the UK do not arrange for their work to be reviewed by someone who understands tax. Politicians are characterised by grandstanding and soundbites. Pressure groups grind their axes.

(3) The factual knowledge problem If discussing particular instancies, one needs to know the facts, which are not usually in the public domain.

Significance and recognition of distinctions

The distinctions I have drawn are not easy, but they are the best that can be achieved.

The ordinary tax planning/tax avoidance dividing line is established in tax law. It marks the point where:

(1) Tax motive provisions begin to bite.[15]

(2) Extra-statutory concessions cease to apply.

(3) HMRC Manuals cease to bind HMRC.[16]


A tax avoidance/tax abuse distinction is new to tax law, but it marks the point at which the GAAR[17] is intended[18] to bite:


The Government agrees with the Report's recommendation to introduce a rule which is targeted at artificial and abusive arrangements (those that the Report refers to as "egregious", "very aggressive" or "highly abusive contrived and artificial"). It accepts the Report's conclusion that introducing a "broad spectrum" general anti-avoidance rule would not be beneficial for the UK tax system. ... the GAAR should not affect what the Report describes as "the centre ground of tax planning".[19]


There has not been much judicial discussion (the issue has not arisen for decision) but a passage in Furniss v Dawson recognises something like a tax avoidance/abuse distinction:


The scheme [in Furniss] has none of the extravagances of certain tax avoidance schemes which have recently engaged the attention of the courts, where the taxpayer who has been fortunate enough to realise a capital profit has gone out into the street and, with the aid of astute advisers, manufactured out of a string of artificial transactions a supposed loss in order to counteract the profit which he has already made. The scheme before your Lordships is a simple and honest scheme which merely seeks to defer payment of tax until the taxpayer has received into his hands the gain which he has made.[20]


The uncontroversial/ordinary tax planning distinction is not relevant in tax law, but it is relevant to the public debate on morality.

Tax avoidance and morality

Morality and taxation

This is intended to be a practical work. The relationship between morality and law (or tax-morality and tax law) is another book. But attitudes to the (im)morality of tax avoidance do have a practical aspect: it affects judicial attitudes and decisions; it was the main motivator for the enactment of the GAAR and will play an important role in its interpretation.

The topic of the relationship between morality and taxation should be seen as part of a wider discussion of the relationship between morality and law. Without entering into these deep waters, it should generally be accepted that not everything which is immoral should be proscribed by law.


Judicial views

Older cases do not appear hostile to tax avoidance. In 1900:


Bundey J. recognises to the full both the legal and the moral right of every man to dispose of his property if he can in a way which does not expose it to be taxed under the existing system of taxation.[21]


In 1965:


The fact that a settlement is drawn with a view to avoiding particular charging provisions is neither reprehensible, nor a proper ground for inclination to a conclusion that it ought to come within those or some other charging provisions. ... If any moral criticism could be levelled at them, then the consciences of the judges of the Chancery Division, in the exercise of their discretionary jurisdiction under the Variation of Trusts Act 1958, would be in a sorry state.[22]


Lord Diplock expressed the traditional view in 1964:


Tax law no more lies within the field of morals than does a crossword puzzle.[23]


Likewise in 1982:


the fact that the purpose of the scheme was tax avoidance does not carry any implication that it was in any way reprehensible or other than perfectly honest and respectable.[24]


Without attempting a full survey, it appears that similar views were held throughout the common law world. In America in 1947:


Over and over again courts have said that there is nothing sinister in so arranging one's affairs as to keep taxes as low as possible. Everybody does so, rich or poor; and all do right, for nobody owes any public duty to pay more than the law demands: taxes are enforced exactions, not voluntary contributions. To demand more in the name of morals is mere cant.[25]


In Australia in 1995:


The obligation to pay [income tax] is a legal one. Some politicians try to treat it as a moral obligation. But it is not. The citizen is bound to pay no more tax than the statute requires him to pay according to the relevant state of his affairs.
Consistently with this view, it has long been a principle of the law of income taxation that the citizen may so arrange his affairs as to render him less liable to pay tax than would be the case if his affairs were cast in some different form. In the language of the layman, the citizen is entitled to minimise his liability to pay tax. This is sometimes expressed as a right to avoid tax...[26]


The following points can be made in favour of the traditional view.

(1) The nature of the tax system The tax system is full of anomalies, artificial, arbitrary, and not based on any consistent principles. That suggests that there is no "right" amount of tax except in the sense of what is due by statute.

(2) HMRC practice When the boot is on the other foot, HMRC take advantage of anomalies in their favour. The unfortunate Mr Lobler fell into the trap[27] of a partial surrender of life policies:


Mr. Lobler invested some US $1.4 million in a series of life assurance policies ... and within the next two years withdrew $1.4 million from the policies leaving the policies with comparatively negligible value. The form in which he made the withdrawal was by a partial surrender of each policy. As a result of the tax legislation ... he is treated as having in those years realised taxable income of some $1.3 million. He becomes liable to pay some $560,000 in tax. He made no profit or gain as that term is commonly or commercially understood and yet he becomes liable to pay tax which exhausts his life savings and may bankrupt him. That is an outrageously unfair result....
This is legislation which does not seek to tax real or commercial gains. Thus it makes no sense to say that the legislation must be construed to apply to transactions by reference to their commercial substance….No overriding principle can be extracted from the legislation....
Thus with heavy hearts we dismiss the appeal.[28]


This is the point made in one of the best known dicta in taxation:


No man in this country is under the smallest obligation, moral or other, so to arrange his legal relations to his business or to his property as to enable the Inland Revenue to put the largest possible shovel into his stores. The Inland Revenue is not slow - and quite rightly - to take every advantage which is open to it under the taxing Statutes for the purpose of depleting the taxpayer's pocket. And the taxpayer is in like manner entitled to be astute to prevent, so far as he honestly can, the depletion of his means by the Revenue.[29]


HMRC say that this has changed:


[The above quote] epitomises the approach which Parliament has rejected in enacting the GAAR legislation. Taxation is not to be treated as a game[30] where taxpayers can indulge in any ingenious scheme in order to eliminate or reduce their tax liability.[31]


At the abuse end of the spectrum the GAAR now applies, so the rules have indeed changed. But I am not sure why it should be said that anything else has changed. Ayshire itself was not an abuse case (the issue was whether the taxpayer's children had entered into a valid partnership) and the result would not have been affected by the GAAR. It also continues to be the case that HMRC take advantage of anomalies in their favour.


(3) Difficulty of applying moral principles The view that taxation is governed by moral principles distinct from black letter tax law either:

(a) requires one to enter into the intractable distinction of tax avoidance/abuse; or

(b) spreads the net very wide, far wider than any practitioner is likely to accept (and still requires one to enter into the intractable distinction of uncontroversial/ordinary tax planning).


In practice, public debate does not engage with black letter tax law and it is difficult to envisage that it ever would, or could. Ethics is a practical subject. It only works if there are two entities called "right" and "wrong" which are reasonably distinguishable and of a more or less permanent nature. If standards are so vague, or so difficult to apply in actual cases, that we cannot see how we could act on them, we become sceptical. That suggests that morality has little if any role to play.


(4) Tax avoidance sometimes leads to a fair result There are cases where tax avoidance avoids unfair tax rules. An example is the use of multiple policies to avoid the tax trap of partial surrender.[32]

Parliament sometimes admits this, by enacting a new relief to allow directly what had previously been achieved by avoidance. Examples are:

(a) Nil rate band discretionary trusts, which allowed transferable nil rate bands before the IHT relief was enacted in 2007.

(b) CGT group relief to obtain loss relief. A company about to realise a gain on an asset would formerly transfer it to a group company that had realised an allowable loss. Alternatively, a company which had realised a gain might acquire from a group company an asset which was to be sold at a loss. That would allow the loss to be set against the gain before the introduction of the election to allocate gains and losses around a group, in 2009.[33]


Offshore trusts mitigate the deleterious lock-in effect of CGT by deferring tax until gains are received.

Tax avoidance (if it be such) sometimes permits a business to continue which would otherwise be destroyed by taxation.[34]

High tax rates may be mitigated by avoidance, achieving a pragmatic compromise between incompatible political viewpoints, or allowing a public perception which is different from the reality. The IFS say:[35]


... in principle, it would be efficient to tax relatively mobile activities at a lower rate in order to avoid deterring mobile activities while allowing a higher rate to be supported on less mobile activities.[36] Avoidance behaviours are one way that de facto lower rates on more mobile income are achieved. ... In this case, there may even be benefits to the UK from avoidance opportunities if the lower tax rates achieved on mobile activities – for example, through profit shifting – mean that more real activity is in the UK than would otherwise be the case.[37]


This fudge has its costs, including the inefficiencies that arise from tax planning, fiscal instability and public cynicism; but it often happens.

Practitioner/judicial views today

In earlier times there was plenty of tax avoidance but little (if any) activity in the category of tax abuse. When that changed, I think in the 1970's, attitudes changed too. By 2007:


For many directors, the objection to arrangements that are in their view 'too' artificial may be framed largely in terms of business ethics. Other directors, equally determined to behave in an ethical way, may consider that the degree of artificiality is not an ethical issue provided no attempt is made to misrepresent the facts or to hide them from the tax authorities....
At one time such a view would perhaps have been more widely held than now. At the present time it represents one end of a range of views in a debate where probably most commentators would hold that within the compass of what is legal there is some behaviour that is acceptable and some that is not...[38]


In 2011, Aaronson's GAAR study reported the views of taxpayer representative bodies:


There was unanimous disapproval, indeed distaste, for egregious tax avoidance schemes.[39]


Of course tax practitioners do not all share the same view. But I think it is the case that they are mostly drawn to the view that opprobrium should only attach at the top end of the scale, in cases of tax abuse; or if any opprobrium attaches to tax motivated behaviours lower down the scale, the amount of opprobrium should vary according to the scale.

This might be consistent with Lord Templeman's views in tax abuse cases, which were expressed trenchantly (some would say, stridently[40]):


In common with my predecessors I regard tax-avoidance schemes of the kind invented and implemented in the present case as no better than attempts to cheat the Revenue.[41]


This may be consistent with a comment of the Supreme Court in 2014:


Since the seminal decision of the House of Lords in Ramsay v IRC[42] there has been an increasingly strong and general recognition that artificial tax avoidance is a social evil which puts an unfair burden on the shoulders of those who do not adopt such measures.[43]


Evil is a strong word, even if constrained by "social"; though the scope of the comment depends on the word "artificial", which may mean little or much.[44]


And again in 2015, but perhaps more moderately expressed:

[Tax avoidance] gives rise to social costs which are significant and increasingly controversial.[45]


This comment, or its implication, has not been enthusiastically adopted. In Altus Group v Baker Tilly negligent accountants argued it was contrary to public policy to award damages for their failure to advise or implement an avoidance scheme. The argument was summarily rejected.[46] In a Guernsey case, an ill-advised gift to an EBT was set aside for mistake. The fact that the individual was participating in a scheme to avoid UK tax was not a reason for the Guernsey Court to refuse the remedy.[47]

Views outside tax profession

Outside the tax profession, the concept of what is unacceptable/immoral is not restricted to tax abuse, but extends to the ordinary tax planning level. That is, some very ordinary tax planning has come under fire. Tax practitioners might dismiss those views as unworthy of consideration. I give four examples from those whose views carry some weight.

Deferring bonus in order to take advantage of announced reduction in tax rates: This arose in 2013/14 when top rates fell from 50% to 45%. Practitioner-readers are likely to agree that this is ordinary tax planning near the bottom end of the scale. But Mervyn King, then Governor of the Bank of England, is reported to have criticised Goldman Sachs for it.[48] The House of Lords select committee noted that the GAAR will not apply to the deferral of bonuses from one tax year to another,[49] but one might infer that they disapproved none the less for that.

The Bump Plan In 2013 a minor political furore arose after David Heaton was secretly filmed, suggesting bonus payments to pregnant employees; if made during the relevant period this would increase the amount of statutory maternity pay.[50] I do not think practitioners would regard that as on the abusive side of the line (though there are many points which need to be made to properly understand the legal and moral analysis, none of which were heard in the public debate).[51] The point was not just political hot air: Heaton had to resign from the GAAR panel following criticism from David Gauke (Exchequer Secretary to the Treasury).

Income sharing with a spouse I think practitioners were surprised that HMRC found this unacceptable in their (ultimately unsuccessful) attack in Jones v Garnett. But exactly the same planning has been criticised in India:


While tax evasion is universally condemned, there is a disposition in certain quarters to regard tax avoidance as a permissible course of action. We are unable to endorse this view. The mere fact that the income-tax law is not violated does not mean that the procedure which results in tax avoidance is justified. We might take as an illustration the act of introducing, without adequate consideration, one's wife ... as partner in a business of which the assessee himself is a partner. It is an attempt to fraction income and reduce tax liability under a provision of law meant to apply to genuine partnerships. Conduct of this nature, though legal, cannot but be regarded as anti-social.[52]


Gift of company to political party A donor who owns a suitable company might arrange that:

(1) The donor gives the company to the political party.

(2) The political party extracts the funds by way of dividend.


The gift at stage (1) qualifies for CGT hold-over relief; and the distribution at stage (2) would not be taxable, assuming the party is a company for tax purposes.

It seems that Labour arranged this in 2013, giving rise to a fit of indignation, or purported indignation, from the Tories. An open letter from George Osborne to Ed Milliband provided:


... the Labour Party has gone to great lengths to help your biggest donor, ... avoid paying tax on a political donation. ...
The Labour Party registered a donation of shares in JML worth £1.65 million in January 2013, from Mr John Mills. By making a donation in shares rather than as a single cash dividend, it has been reported that Mr Mills managed to avoid a potential tax charge of £724,710.[53] ...
As leader of the Labour Party, and given your previous statements on tax avoidance, such actions by your party appear to be directly at odds with your public statements.
Most importantly, will you now pass the amount of tax that has been avoided to the Exchequer? As you say, this is money that is needed to fund vital public services such as the health service and our schools.[54]


What is one to make of this? I think any practitioner, or anyone who understood the tax background, would regard this as in the category of "sensible tax planning" or, perhaps, ordinary tax planning; in either case, well short of avoidance and opprobrium. The letter could be seen as just an example of debased political debate, meaningless playground insults whose object is just to knock the opposition. It could be taken as a case where ordinary tax planning is regarded as immoral. However, it may be regarded as an illustration of the difficulties which arise if one regards taxation as governed by moral principles distinct from black letter tax law. The letter might then be regarded as a rather subtle and well aimed contribution to the political/moral debate. Perhaps there are elements of each of these.


In short, there is widespread disagreement about the starting point, not to mention finish line, when it comes to avoidance.

Context of discussion

It is possible to discuss tax-morality in a lofty, disinterested and high-minded way. What is the good life? What would Aristotle say?

But in practice discussion is invested with flaming indignation, which comes to be fuelled by hatred for those who support and connive with these injustices. This is fed by a sense of superiority that we are not like these instruments and accomplices of evil. The result is moral panic, contempt, hatred and aggression.[55] The remedies proposed become ever more penal and more discretionary.

The debate sometimes suffers from profound bad faith or hypocrisy. Politicians accuse others of tax-immorality in order to attack their opponents or promote themselves: see the letter to Ed Miliband above. Journalists do so for a headline to sell papers.


Professional practice

Accountants and regulatory bodies now boast of their tax-morality. For instance, KPMG's Tax Principles provide:


We will interpret legislation in a purposive way in line with the courts. We will not advise clients to enter into transactions with the main purpose of securing a tax advantage clearly contrary to the intention of Parliament in enacting the relevant legislation.


Who would interpret legislation other than in line with the courts? And such advice would be caught by the GAAR: who could properly give such advice? A reader well-informed about taxation may be tempted to say, with Scrooge: Bah, humbug. But there are not many such readers, and the code is not designed for them.

This raises a further set of issues arises in relation to practitioners who act in tax avoidance cases. There are conflicting normative visions of the lawyer's role, raising the basic question: can a good lawyer be a good person? For legal practitioners, client autonomy is a fundamental value. That view is not usually accepted, or understood, by the general public or by HMRC.[56] A whole book would be needed to discuss the topic.[57]

The SRA have jumped on the bandwagon by issuing a “Warning” entitled “Tax avoidance - your duties”[58]

In the House of Lords case of Ayrshire Pullman v CIR, Lord Clyde said that "No man in this country is under the smallest obligation, moral or other, so as to arrange his legal relations to his business or to his property as to enable the Inland Revenue to put the largest possible shovel into his stores." That approach has been rejected by Parliament by bringing in the General Anti-Abuse Rule (GAAR) 2013 legislation.

This is not correct.[59]

GAAR is clearly explained in HMRC guidance.

This is not correct.

Similarly, the widespread assumption that “tax avoidance is legal” no longer applies.

This is not correct.[60]


It seems safe to infer that text of the warning was composed by HMRC.

While much contemporary politics is characterised by shallow thinking[61] and misinformation, perhaps inevitably so, it is dispiriting to see the same applies to the SRA.

Conclusion

In conclusion, there is no consensus on issues of morality in connection with tax avoidance, and no prospect of reaching one. This should not be a surprise, since the same applies to many contemporary moral issues, for instance, assisted suicide. There is no tribunal to adjudicate arguments on morality, except the court of public opinion, which, as Ibsen observed, is an extremely mutable thing.


Amount lost by avoidance

Another common thread in public debate is a vast estimate of the amounts involved. HMRC publish figures called "the tax gap":


It estimated that at 31 March 2012 up to £35 billion of tax was at risk or under consideration due to avoidance or legal interpretation.[62]


The words "or legal interpretation"[63] make the figure meaningless as a measure of avoidance, but for a critique of the methodology, see Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation "The Tax Gap for Corporation Tax".[64]

The IFS say:


we don't know how much corporate tax is lost to the UK as a result of tax avoidance. This is partly because there is no accepted definition of exactly what constitutes 'avoidance' and partly because we lack full information about the activities of firms.[65]


Of course, the fact that an amount is unknown and unknowable does not mean that it is small or unimportant. There is no doubt that the amounts involved are significant. I doubt if time spent guessing at figures is productive.

The IFS report continues:


Importantly, even if we knew that information and could calculate the tax lost to avoidance, it would not be right to assume that, were all avoidance opportunities to be completely removed, the UK would be able to collect that full amount. We would expect higher taxes to feed through, at least to some degree, to lower investment and changes in prices such that genuine UK profits may be lower. To the extent that the corporate tax affects prices or wages, or the location of firms' activities (and therefore jobs), there may also be lower receipts from income taxes or VAT.


This is true for all taxes, but particularly for corporation tax:


First, corporation tax is a particularly distortionary form of taxation that can work to reduce investment. This is especially the case for internationally mobile investments because firms will consider tax when choosing where to locate real activities...
Second, the ultimate incidence of corporate tax always lies with households and is borne either by the owners of capital (in the form of lower dividends), by workers (in the form of lower wages) or by consumers (in the form of higher prices). We do not know with any precision who is made worse off as the result of the corporation tax. However, estimates suggest that, because capital tends to be much more mobile than workers or consumers, a significant share of the burden of corporate tax tends to be shifted to domestic factors – and specifically labour. In other words, there is reason to believe that at least a part, and in some cases a large part, of the corporation tax that companies are subject to is ultimately passed on to workers in the form of lower wages.[66]


There is a certain irony in the second point, given the left's enthusiasm for corporation tax, but economists do generally accept that the burden of corporation tax is borne by employees.[67]

The rule of law

What is "the rule of law"

There is a consensus on the rule of law. It is a "constitutional principle".[68] It is one of four "fundamental British values"[69] and one of the six values on which the EU is founded.[70]

There is no consensus on the meaning of the phrase. It is an emotionally charged label for a set of principles, or sub-principles, the content of which is contested. This may not be a bad thing: the consensus on the rule of law is only possible because of dissensus as to its meaning. There is a certain irony in that the principle which forbids vague legislation is itself difficult to pin down. But the same is true of other cherished political virtues, such as democracy. A discussion needs a book to itself;[71] but as the term is used in different ways, it is best not to use it without some explanation of how it should be, or may be, understood. This section draws on the paper by Craig, "The Rule of Law" prepared for the Select Committee on Constitution.[72]

There is a consensus that the rule of law includes at least the following minimum requirements.[73]

Craig says:


The Rule of Law and Lawful Authority
A core idea of the rule of law to which all would subscribe is that the government must be able to point to some basis for its action that is regarded as valid by the relevant legal system. Thus in the UK such action would commonly have its foundation in statute, the prerogative or in common law power.


It follows that tax must be imposed by parliament through legislation.

Craig continues:


The Rule of Law and Guiding Conduct
A further important aspect of the rule of law is that the laws thus promulgated should be capable of guiding ones conduct in order that one can plan ones life.
It is from this general precept that Raz deduced a number of more specific attributes that laws should have in order that they could be said to comply with the rule of law. All are related to the idea of enabling individuals to be able to plan their lives. The 'list' includes the following
(1) laws should be prospective, not retrospective;
(2) they should be relatively stable;
(3) particular laws should be guided by open, general and clear rules;[74]
(4) there should be an independent judiciary;
(5) there should be access to the courts;
(6) the discretion which law enforcement agencies possess should not be allowed to undermine the purposes of the relevant legal rules.

Rule of law v. other values

The rule of law is something to boast of,[75] and a feature which makes the UK an attractive place to reside, invest, or litigate. The Judicial Office boast:


The Rule of Law represents the cornerstone of liberty and democracy, and is one of the main reasons that the UK attracts global businesses and investors.
Laws in the UK are:
  • public (so that everyone knows what they say)
  • certain (so that everyone knows where they stand)
  • prospective rather than retrospective (so that they cannot be broken before they exist)[76]


If only! Rule of law principles are challenged, or breached, in various aspects of taxation;[77] and the conflict with tax avoidance is particularly deep. Anti-avoidance is facilitated by techniques which breach the rule of law:

(1) Administrative discretion

(2) Vague legislation

(3) Retrospective legislation


It is desirable to recognise that there is a trade-off between two policy aims, the rule of law and the combat of avoidance, rather than to fudge the matter by saying, or pretending, that these techniques are consistent with the rule of law. Then one can face the choice aware of the consequences of one choice or another. Craig says:


... the rule of law in the above sense is only one virtue of a legal system, and may have to be sacrificed to attain other desired ends. We may feel that the rule of law virtues of having clear, general laws should be sacrificed if the best or only way to achieve a desired goal is to have more discretionary, open-textured legal provisions. This may be so where it is not possible to lay down in advance in the enabling legislation clear rules in sufficient detail to cover all eventualities. Modifications to the rule of law in this manner are not somehow forbidden or proscribed. Given that it is only one virtue of a legal system it should not prevent the attainment of other virtues valued by that system.


In 1974, Lord Simon placed the rule of law above the need to combat tax avoidance:


Disagreeable as it may seem that some taxpayers should escape what might appear to be their fair share of the general burden of national expenditure, it would be far more disagreeable to substitute the rule of caprice for that of law.[78]


The cure could be worse than the disease. In contemporary UK debate it is rare to find a statement in such strong terms. An exception comes from the Joint Committee on Statutory Instruments, discussing this provision:


If—
(a) a person enters into any arrangements; and
(b) the main purpose, or one of the main purposes, of the person in entering into the arrangements is to avoid any obligation under these Regulations,
these Regulations are to have effect as if the arrangements had not been entered into.[79]


The Committee said:


... people who are satisfied that the terms of the regulations do not apply to them will be at constant risk of HMRC initially concluding that they have attempted to avoid the regulations and that the regulations therefore apply anyway – that being the default position in the absence of an appeal. It is unclear that such a result, which breaches the principle of certainty, would be within the contemplation of enabling powers that do not contain express provision for the type of anti-avoidance provision used.
The fact that Parliament has, notably in Part 5 of the Finance Act 2013, [the GAAR] enacted anti-avoidance provisions which are similarly imprecise or discretionary is irrelevant to the security of such provisions in subordinate legislation, in the absence of express enabling powers.
The Committee accordingly reports regulation 21 for a doubt as to whether it is intra vires.[80]


But this example also illustrates the weakness of the rule of law in the UK:

(1) Regulation 21, whose validity is in doubt, remains in the legislation.[81]

(2) Identical wording is found in:

(a) reg 23 International Tax Compliance Regulations 2015.[82]
(b) The residence property TAAR.[83]


Tax avoidance is an issue of international tax as well as domestic tax, and in the US, the rule of law may perhaps be more highly valued. Bob Stack (US Treasury Deputy Assistant Secretary for International Tax Affairs) criticised the OECD BEPS reforms, and UK diverted profits tax, for breaching the rule of law and international tax law principles:


Rather than producing administrable rules, the BEPS negotiators seemed to be opting instead for giving wide discretion to tax officials.[84] This brought into question the whole international tax system. Do the international tax rules even matter anymore? Do we really need a standard setter to say, 'Tax administrators can use the pornography test to catch tax avoidance. We know it when we see it. And we will get you if we want to'?...
[Diverted Profits Tax] ... took us further down the road in which a taxpayer is at the mercy of whatever a tax auditor decides is the right amount to pay. What made this particularly perturbing was that these measures emanated not from the usual suspects such as India, China, Brazil and South Africa, but from strong traditional residence countries [UK and Australia] that happened to be two of our closest friends.[85]

Consequence of breach of rule of law

Craig says:

... the consequences of breach of the rule of law in the sense considered in this section. The fact that a law is vague or unclear, and that it therefore provides little by way of real guidance for those affected by it, will not lead to a statute being invalidated in the UK. The courts may well interpret such a statute narrowly, in favour of the individual in such circumstances. They might also read it down pursuant to the Human Rights Act 1998, if the particular statute would otherwise infringe rights derived from the European Convention on Human Rights. If the courts felt unable to read it down, they could issue a declaration of incompatibility under the HRA, and the matter would be sent back to Parliament for reconsideration. The courts therefore have considerable interpretive techniques at their disposal to ensure that legislation that fails to meet the requirements of the rule of law set out above is construed narrowly in favour of the individual. This does not alter the fact that UK courts have not traditionally exerted power to invalidate an Act of Parliament on such grounds.



In relation to secondary legislation (statutory instruments) the courts could in theory strike down provisions on the grounds of breach of the rule of law (which might be said to be ultra vires, in the absence of very clear or direct authority in the authorising act of parliament) but in practice as far as I know it has never happened.

In other words, the rule of law lacks full justiciability. Perhaps confusingly, or ironically, the Rule of Law is not in the strict sense a rule of law. But however deeply, inchoately, and inconsistently, the rule of law still to some extent affects tax policy and case law outcomes.

UK tax: rule of law complaint

As the rule of law is a set of principles, this issue raises a set of almost impossibly broad questions.

In earlier editions[86] of this book, I said:


The UK tax system is largely[87] based on the rule of law rather than informal practice and discretion.

By the 13th edition (2014) I qualified the boast:


However, that is less the case than formerly, due to:
(1) wide, complex, or vague anti-avoidance provisions mitigated by informal practice, HMRC guidance, HMRC discretion or oversight.
(2) retrospective legislation.[88]


In 2014 the City of London Law Society said:


2.4 ... tax policymakers are insufficiently conscious of the importance of the rule of law – that is, the constitutional right of a citizen to determine the law applicable to him at any given date. Related to this is a similar problem of lack of respect for legislation as the only proper source of law, and over-reliance on guidance.[89]


In 2015 the Law Society makes the same point:


... in recent years, there has been a tendency on the part of government to allow the rule of law in taxation to risk being eroded in the interests of making the executive more effective, in particular in seeking to combat avoidance...


The following examples draw on the lists of these bodies supplemented by my own:

(1) The absence of a right to appeal so obligations are determined by HMRC discretion:

(a) The Banking Code of Practice on Taxation; there is no right of appeal against HMRC determination of a breach of the code.
(b) Follower notices: there is no right of appeal against the issue of such a notice on a number of important grounds.

(2) Retrospective taxation.

(3) Uncertainty in tax law. Sometimes this may be deliberate. For instance, Jim Harra, Director General, Business Tax at HMRC applauds the uncertainty of the proposed GAAR:


It will also create an additional level of uncertainty for the promoters and users of schemes. I believe that that will be a deterrent.[90]


(4) Anti-avoidance legislation drafted widely and then cut down by HMRC concession mislabeled as guidance. Examples include:

(a) s.30 FA 2014 (avoidance by transfer of corporate profits)


(b) The CGT loss TAAR.[91]

TAARs

TAAR stands for “targeted anti-avoidance rule”. It is used to describe unallowable purpose tests in specific UK tax codes (as opposed to the GAAR, which applies throughout taxation).

This term was coined by HMRC and first used in a press release of 5 December 2005. Before then the term used was motive (or purpose) test. In the older TAARs, such as the ToA and TiS motive defences, those remain the standard terms.


The number of TAARs is very large.[92]


I would distinguish three types of TAAR, depending on the nature of the unallowable purpose test. I coin the following terminology to describe them:

Style of TAAR Unallowable purpose expressed as
Avoidance-purpose TAAR Tax avoidance (in its strict sense)
Tax-advantage TAAR Obtaining a tax advantage (not requiring avoidance in strict sense)
Application (or effect) TAAR Avoiding the application (or effect) of specified provisions


A tax-advantage style TAAR is very wide, if one understands “tax advantage” to include cases where there is no element of tax avoidance.


An application/effect style TAAR may be wider still. In the view of the Joint Committee on Statutory Instruments, this wording is too wide and vague.[93] But HMRC do not take any notice of that. It continues to be a common form (perhaps the most common form) for new TAARs.


Although there is a variation of wording, TAARs share a common framework, or there are at least 3 common sets of frameworks, and cases on one TAAR may shed light on others. The most litigated is the TiS purpose test, though in recent years there have been many cases on the loan relationships TAAR.

"Tax advantage"

The expression “tax advantage” is used in (what I call) tax-advantage style TAARs. It is defined on each occasion. There is no single standard definition, but the definitions generally adopt common form wording, with minor variations, so it is helpful to consider the definitions together as a single topic.


In this definition the word “tax” is generally restricted to specified taxes, but that is not addressed here.


Standard IT/CGT definition of "tax advantage"

The expression was first used in the TiS purpose test in 1960, and that definition survives in the current CT version of the rules. Section 732(1) CTA 2010 provides:

In this Part “corporation tax advantage” means—
(a) a relief from corporation tax or increased relief from corporation tax,
(b) a repayment of corporation tax or increased repayment of corporation tax,
(c) the avoidance or reduction of a charge to corporation tax or an assessment to corporation tax, or
(d) the avoidance of a possible assessment to corporation tax.


I refer to this as “the standard IT/CGT definition” of tax advantage.


GAAR definition of "tax advantage"

Section 208 FA 2013 provides:

A “tax advantage” includes—
(a) relief or increased relief from tax,
(b) repayment or increased repayment of tax,
(c) avoidance or reduction of a charge to tax or an assessment to tax,
(d) avoidance of a possible assessment to tax,
(e) deferral of a payment of tax or advancement of a repayment of tax, and
(f) avoidance of an obligation to deduct or account for tax.


I refer to this as “the GAAR definition” of tax advantage.


The GAAR definition is wider than the TiS definition in three respects:

(1) It has become an inclusive definition. But since it is so widely defined, it is not easy to think of anything which is a tax advantage which does not fall within paras (a) to (f).

(2) Paras (e) and (f) are added.

(3) The word “tax” is widely defined. Section 206(3) FA 2013 provides:

(3) The general anti-abuse rule applies to the following taxes—
(a) income tax,
(b) corporation tax, including any amount chargeable as if it were corporation tax or treated as if it were corporation tax,
(c) capital gains tax,
(d) petroleum revenue tax,
(da) diverted profits tax,
(e) inheritance tax,
(f) stamp duty land tax, and
(g) annual tax on enveloped dwellings.


Post-2013 anti-avoidance provisions often adopt the GAAR definition by reference (though generally with a narrower definition of “tax”).


IHT definition of "tax advantage"

Section 162A(8) IHTA defines tax advantage:

In this section ...
“tax advantage” means—
(a) the avoidance or reduction of a charge to tax, or
(b) the avoidance of a possible determination in respect of tax.


I refer to this as “the standard IHT definition”.


This based on the standard TiS definition of tax advantage adapted as appropriate for IHT.

Retrospective tax legislation

This topic deserves a section to itself.

Retrospective legislation: Extent

Examples include:


(1) Retrospective reversal of avoidance schemes; for examples see:


(a) DT relief for partnership
(b) s.23 FA 2012 (loan relationships)
It is perhaps only a slight exaggeration to say that retrospective tax legislation has become a matter of routine, having been applied to a somewhat arbitrary selection of tax avoidance schemes.


(2) Legislation not retrospective in its wording, but retrospective in effect in that it is designed to affect arrangements carried out under old law, or (deliberately or otherwise) lacks fair and appropriate transitional provisions. Examples include:


(a) Pre-owned assets (2004)[94]
(b) IHT treatment of former Accumulation & Maintenance trusts (2006)
(c) Aspects of the ITA remittance rules (2008)[95]

(3) It has also become common as second thoughts to (what the need for retrospective legislation shows to be) ill thought out legislation; but insofar as retrospective legislation favours the taxpayer, perhaps it is less objectionable on rule of law grounds.

Retrospective legislation: Protocol

In Budget 2011, the coalition Government published a statement (grandly labelled a "protocol") on retrospective legislation. The most important part provides:


The Government has made clear its aim to strike the right balance between

[1] restoring the UK tax system's reputation for predictability, stability and simplicity(!) and [2] preserving its ability to protect the Exchequer by making changes where necessary. In particular, changes to tax legislation where the change takes effect from a date earlier than the date of announcement will be wholly exceptional.[96]

The attempt to formulate the principles behind a decision to enact retrospective legislation is to be applauded. But the sanction (if any) for ignoring the protocol is political only. It is not enforceable in the courts. That is self-evident; but if authority is needed:

The Protocol was an extra-statutory announcement or promise made by the government. As such, it operated: in the realm of politics, not of the courts, and the question whether the government should be held to such a promise is a political rather than a legal matter... The sovereignty of Parliament cannot be confined by extra-statutory promises like the Protocol.[97]


I think it as it should be: this is a matter for parliament and not for the courts.

The 2011 statement does not purport to bind future governments. The Cameron administration (May 2015 - July 2016) did not resile from it, but whether the current or subsequent administrations will follow it remains to be seen.

Retrospective legislation: Validity

All authorities discussing the rule of law agree that it includes a prohibition of retrospective legislation, so there is no doubt that such legislation breaches the rule of law. As noted above, it is not for that reason rendered invalid as the rule of law is not justiciable as such. Human Rights challenges have not been successful.[98]

Retrospective legislation: Politics

Various reasons have been given to justify retrospective legislation.[99]

One is that the scheme will fail (or so the Government believe). If that is true, the change is unnecessary; if not (and it is generally debatable) it is not a good reason.

Another is that the scheme is abusive (however that flexible term may be understood). Whether that justifies retrospective legislation is ultimately a political question on which views differ depending on how much one values the rule of law. It is arbitrary and unfair in that a few particular schemes are retrospectively stopped and others – no less elaborate, artificial and abusive – are not. Pragmatists (to whom the rule of law is of little interest) should bear in mind that retrospective legislation increases the "legal risk", a measure under which the UK falls low on international surveys, and the lowering of the UK's reputation in that regard has a significant albeit intangible cost. I suspect a major factor in picking on some arrangements may be the amount of money involved.

Retrospective legislation: Future

How often will retrospective legislation be used in the future? What advice can anyone give to taxpayers seeking to know their position? Prior to the enactment of the GAAR, I said:


Much depends on the politics of the day, but I guess that retrospective legislation will continue to be a rare response; a popular scheme carried out by many taxpayers and involving larger sums is certainly more at risk than others.[100]


The compatibility of the GAAR with the rule of law is open to debate, on the grounds of vagueness in particular. But one positive consequence may be (and should be) to end the practice of retrospective anti-avoidance legislation altogether; wholly retrospective legislation should no longer be necessary. But partially retrospective legislation, in the form of unfair commencement rules, will no doubt continue.

Naming and shaming

"Naming and shaming" covers a variety of arrangements. The FA 2014 provisions to name and shame the promoters of tax avoidance schemes and the Code of Practice on Taxation of Banks raise concerns, but the greatest concern is the practice in the media.


The OUCBT paper provides:


... searching for individual or corporate villains will not assist in remedying the underlying problems...


Even if public naming and shaming influences a few taxpayers in the public eye to impose their own voluntary constraints, it will not necessarily affect the worst avoiders, and may even encourage some non-compliance from those who feel that "everyone is at it". Only understanding the flaws in the tax system and working on serious changes can give long-term results....


Even if that were to have an effect on one taxpayer it would not tackle the underlying issues.


No-one has taken any notice of that! Naming and shaming is at present common for various purposes (more than one may be present at the same time):

(1) In marketing: To sell newspapers with exposures of celebrities who have been involved in tax avoidance schemes.[101]

(2) In politics, to knock the opposition by alleging that politicians, or other party supporters, are guilty of tax avoidance. In this respect, anything goes and some stories have been farcical. Thus in 2015 Mandelson was berated for taking a loan from a UK company.[102] Ed Miliband was accused of avoiding tax by means of a deed of variation.[103] The allegations are so off-target as to cast doubt the good faith of those who make them and newspapers which uncritically promote them.

(3) As a scandalisation technique, to promote the view that avoidance is immoral; often combined with juxtaposition of avoidance and evasion and the suggestion that there is little or no difference.


When these allegations are made it is impossible to defend oneself.


So public debate is not uninformed but misinformed. It is a yeasty mingling of dimly understood facts with vague but deep impressions, and images, half real, half fantastic. It has more than its fair share of misunderstanding and jejune polemics.


In these circumstances, public naming and shaming may quickly lead away from the rule of law. Starbucks paid £20m following the threat to occupy its cafes.[104] If one calls that payment "taxation" at all, it was certainly not taxation imposed by law. A hostile commentator would call this taxation by mob rule. Google and Amazon, who do not have public premises vulnerable to the same threat, have paid nothing.

Avoidance by multinational companies

Much attention has been given to multinational companies. The Public Accounts Committee looked at Starbucks, Amazon and Google. The verdict was guilty.[105]


It is not possible to comment sensibly on the taxation of any multi-national group without knowing the relevant facts, which are not usually in the public domain. The claim that these companies have avoided UK corporation tax is often based on the size of their UK sales or UK staff, set against the corporation tax actually paid. But all well-informed commentators know that corporation tax is not a tax on sales, or the size of an establishment, and large sales/staff does not mean large profits. The OUCBT paper provides:


Starbucks and Facebook ... have been criticized for not paying tax where they are making sales, but sales are not the basis for the corporation tax, so this alone is no cause for criticism of the companies concerned. We could argue that the tax base should change, but unless and until that occurs, the fact that there is a high turnover but no taxable profit is not in itself an indicator that the taxpayer is behaving in an unreasonable way.


Likewise the fact that relatively little CT is paid proves nothing. The OUCBT paper provides:


The fact that there is little or no tax payable is not, however, conclusive evidence that there is effective or ineffective avoidance. In some of these cases, these companies are simply operating in accordance with incentives created by the international tax system and by domestic governments trying to attract economic activity into their jurisdictions. This the governments may do for non-tax reasons, or because this activity gives rise to forms of taxes other than those which are not being collected. ...


The IFS say:


A low corporate tax bill is not in itself therefore evidence of tax avoidance. Even if income appears high, there may be genuinely low UK taxable profits if a firm has relatively high current expenditures or can offset the effects of large investment expenditures or losses. The UK tax bill can also be appropriately relatively low compared with declared income if that income is the result of genuinely non-UK activities.


HMRC make the same point:


Globalisation means that multinationals have the opportunity to structure their business to take advantage of beneficial tax rules in different countries. Provided that this results in profits being taxed in line with where genuine economic activity is carried on, this does not amount to tax avoidance. ... In broad terms, companies are required to pay corporation tax in the country where they carry on the economic activity that generates their profits, not where their customers are located.[106]


Unusually, the facts are known in relation to Apple as a result of US congressional hearings (I suspect, better conducted than the UK equivalent). These have been well analysed by Antony Ting.[107] In short, there is no reason to think that Apple have avoided UK tax. The group has avoided Irish/US tax by Irish/US hybrid companies; and, perhaps, it has reduced Irish tax by informal transfer pricing agreements with the Irish Revenue.


Transfer pricing

It is often said that multinationals engage in avoidance through transfer pricing. For instance, Christian Aid say:


There is debate about the extent to which companies engage in trade mispricing (artificially suppressing the income they earn from activities such as resource extraction, to reduce payments to government), but few would doubt that it has a significant impact on the incomes of governments in the global South.[108]


Transfer pricing is not strictly avoidance. It is in principle in the category of ineffective avoidance:


We may well question whether the transfer pricing rules are adequate, ... but these are considerations relating to tax policy reform and not to tax avoidance.


The fundamental problem is not terminology, but that the facts needed to assess these claims are not in the public domain. Robert Maas says:


The Public Accounts Committee believes that Starbucks overpays for its coffee. I am not an expert on the economics of coffee, but I am a bit puzzled that the PAC members consider themselves sufficiently knowledgeable in this area to be able to pass judgment (sorry, to express scepticism).


The committee thinks that a 16.67% margin to a company that sources and buys coffee throughout the world, exercises quality control and works with local farmers, is excessive. Personally, I do not but then I don't have any expertise in coffee.


The PAC also believes that the rate of interest on the inter-company loan from the US company (4.9%) is excessive, "at a higher rate than any similar loan we have seen". I do not know what similar loans the committee has seen, ie a loan to a loss-making business with little asset backing. I must say it looks modest to me...[109]


If transfer pricing is conducted with the consent of the tax authority concerned, it is not avoidance, though it may be unfair tax competition. The EC are currently pursuing state aid rules;[110] it will be interesting to see what results.

GAAR

The GAAR guidance provides:


Many of the established rules of international taxation are set out in double taxation treaties. These cover, for example,
[1] the attribution of profits to branches or between group companies of multi-national enterprises, and
[2] the allocation of taxing rights to the different states where such enterprises operate.
The fact that arrangements benefit from these rules does not mean that the arrangements amount to abuse, and so the GAAR cannot be applied to them. Accordingly, many cases of the sort which generated a great deal of media and parliamentary debate in the months leading up to the enactment of the GAAR cannot be dealt with by the GAAR.[111]


In my terminology, these issues are non-avoidance, and in some cases, tax avoidance, but not tax abuse.


But where there is abuse, one country's domestic GAAR cannot resolve the issue. Apple's planning, for instance, turned on a hybrid entity:

(1) transparent under Irish tax law, and so not paying tax on its profits in Ireland;

(2) opaque in US tax law, and so not paying tax on its profits in the US.


CIOT say:


As in much of the BEPS project, this is not a case of tax avoidance as previously understood; there can be no avoidance where there is no intent to tax in the first place.[112]


It seems to me that planning with a hybrid entity may properly be described as tax avoidance if it is the case that:

(1) The intention of Oireachtas is that the entity's income should be taxed in the US, and

(2) The intention of US Congress is that the entity's income should be taxed in Ireland.


One might refer to it as international tax avoidance (though there is of course no such tax as "international tax"). The tax advantage is not contrary to the tax policy of either country in isolation; it is the result of a gap between the two.[113] However the gap may in fact be intentional, in that both Ireland and the US deliberately chose to facilitate the planning;[114] in which case the planning should not be called avoidance at all.

BEPS

Whatever the terminology, CIOT are right to say that the tools to deal with multinational planning/avoidance will not be the same as those used for domestic tax avoidance. It is an international problem which only international consensus can resolve.


OECD has been tasked with doing something on the taxation of multinational companies, and has produced an "Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting" and a raft of reports and proposals.[115] It will be interesting to see what emerges. The difficulty of achieving international consensus is considerable:


the OECD had a mandate from G-20, whose members include the BRICS countries, which often disagree with OECD tax policies; the United States, which often goes its own way; and from European finance ministers … who generally don't agree on anything but agree on the need for change ...[116]


We should never lose sight of the fact that public debates about tax avoidance are simultaneously fiscal, moral and political debates, raising issues of equality, redistribution, class, and tax competition; and sensitive ears may also detect elements of xenophobia.

Footnotes

  1. For examples from 1798 and 1920, see "Tax Avoidance in 1798" :http://www.kessler.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2013/06/Tax-avoidance-criticism-in-1798.pdf and "Vestey: Royal Commission evidence and ensuing debate"
    http://www.kessler.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2013/07/Vestey_Royal_Commission_evidence_and_ensuing_debate.pdf.
  2. It is interesting to speculate why that has been the case. I think the reasons lie more in the realm of politics and sociology than tax law and practice. The Public Accounts Committee, and some effective pressure groups, have clearly contributed but given the pressure on the front page, why has their work received so enthusiastic a reception? The 2008 financial crisis and climate of austerity may be a factor.
  3. This side note is included in the version of the speech published online; one wonders what happened when the speech was delivered.
  4. David Cameron speech to World Economic Forum in Davos, January 2013 https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/prime-minister-david-camerons-speech-to-the-world-economic-forum-in-davos
  5. I suspect newspaper libel readers (rightly) insert this if a journalist overlooks it.
  6. This feeds on another very ancient trope concerning lawyers.
  7. "Tax avoidance" (2012) http://www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/sites/default/files/Business_Taxation/Docs/Publications/Reports/TaxGap_3_12_12.pdf (I omit some footnotes here).
  8. For instance, Tiley described "tax planning" as a euphemism for avoidance, which is no doubt sometimes (maybe often) the case.
  9. The paper adopts the somewhat unhelpful labels "categories A, B, and C". It is difficult to find short labels which neatly sum up the concepts: "Ineffective avoidance" is not ideal as this is not really "avoidance" at all.
  10. It may be that a change in public expectation or knowledge is desirable.
  11. There are many ways to slice this cake. Lord Walker proposed seven types of tax avoidance (a riff on Empson's Seven Types of Ambiguity): "Ramsay 25 years on" [2004] LQR 120. Contrast Barnett, "A baker's dozen" Taxation Magazine, 2 August 2012. But one must resist the temptation to taxonomy for its own sake. All classification is (or should be) purposive: a useful taxonomy must draw useful distinctions: it should identify categories which call for different responses, and only those.
  12. In the debate on the Budget 2012, some said that giving more than £50k or 25% of income was excessive.
  13. These are the examples which David Cameron called "sensible tax planning" in the quote at the start of this chapter.
  14. The epithet commonly used is "egregious" or "aggressive". That does not clarify anything but it neatly expresses the point. For completeness: In technical EU-law terminology the term "abuse" is used in a different sense; see Abuse, avoidance, evasion: Terminology; similarly in OECD discussion; see OECD concept of abuse. However we are not concerned with that usage here.
  15. See Avoidance, mitigation, tax reduction, evasion.
  16. HMRC Guidance Manuals introduction: "Subject to [limited specified] qualifications readers may assume the [HMRC Manual] guidance applies in the normal case; but where HMRC considers that there is, or may have been, avoidance of tax the guidance will not necessarily apply." http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/manuals/advisory.htm
  17. In this book references to “the GAAR” are to the general anti-abuse rule in FA 2013. For completeness, there are (at least) two other (rather specialist) GAARs (where the abbreviation stands for general anti-avoidance rule): Part 5 Revenue Scotland and Tax Powers Act 2014; Part 3A Tax Collection and Management (Wales) Act 2016.
  18. The statutory definition (perhaps unavoidably) allows some scope for mission creep. Section 207(2) FA 2013 provides for the purposes of the GAAR: "Tax arrangements are "abusive" if they ... cannot reasonably be regarded as a reasonable course of action...". The extent to which the GAAR will successfully focus on this target remains to be seen. But it is significant that the GAAR is called a general anti-abuse rule, not a general anti-avoidance rule.
  19. HMRC consultation document "A General Anti-Abuse Rule" (2012) para 2.1.
  20. [1984] AC 474 at p.518.
  21. Simms v Registrar of Probates [1900] AC 323 at p.333.
  22. Re Kirkwood [1965] Ch 286 at p.327.
  23. Diplock, "The Courts as Legislators" Address to The Holdsworth Club (1965)
    http://www.kessler.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2012/05/CourtsAsLegistlators.pdf.
  24. IRC v Burmah Oil 54 TC 200 at p.220; followed in 1988 in Craven v White 62 TC 1 at p.196.
  25. Commissioner v Newman, 159 F2d 848 (1947). The case concerned the taxation of settlor-interested trusts.
  26. Sir Garfield Barwick (Chief Justice of Australia 1964–81), A Radical Tory (1995) at p.229.
  27. See Policies: Introduction
  28. Lobler v HMRC [2013] UKFTT 141 (TC); see Firth, "Sauce for the Goose" Taxation Magazine, 4 April 2013. Note that those who strongly support the rule of law should not criticise HMRC for taking the point, though one might criticise them for not seeking to change the law. In order to avoid the unfairness the Upper Tribunal allowed the appeal, though it had to rewrite the law of rectification as previously understood in order to do so. See [2015] UKUT 152 (TCC). But that does not affect the point being made here. The position will have to be reviewed when the case is final.
  29. Ayrshire Pullman Motor Services v IRC 14 TC 754 at p.763 (emphasis added)
  30. The game metaphor begs an essay to itself. What, in fact, is a game? It is an elastic concept which can be analogised in different ways. What is it in the notion of game which HMRC seek to identify as significantly different from tax? Is it a notion of non-seriousness? Or an adversarial approach? Or a notion of a rule based activity? Or arbitrary rules? In the latter three respects, tax law and general law very much resemble games. These problems suggest that it would help clarity of thinking not to use the word "game": a stale and failed metaphor. See Midgley, Heart and Mind (1981) chapter 8 (The game game).
  31. HMRC, "GAAR Guidance" (2015) https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/tax-avoidance-general-anti-abuse-rules. The point is repeated in"Charity tax reliefs: guidance on Charity Commission policy"(2015): "The GAAR makes it clear (!) that taxation is not to be treated as a game where taxpayers can indulge in any contrived or inventive scheme in order to eliminate or reduce their tax liability." https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/charity-tax-reliefs-guidance-on-charity-commission-policy/charity-tax-reliefs-guidance-on-charity-commission-policy.
  32. See Partial surrender trap.
  33. Section 171A TCGA.
  34. For an example, see Fisher v HMRC [2014] UKFTT 805 (TC).
  35. IFS, Green Budget 2013 p.290 http://www.ifs.org.uk/budgets/gb2013/gb2013.pdf
  36. Footnote original: See J. Mirrlees et al., Tax by Design: The Mirrlees Review, (2011) http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesReview/design at p.12.
  37. Footnote original: There is an academic literature on the costs and possible benefits of tax planning. See for example, D. Dharmapala, "What problems and opportunities are created by tax havens?", Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 2008, 24, 661–79.
  38. David Williams "Developing the Concept of Tax Governance" (February 2007) http://webcache.googleusercontent.com/search?q=cache:gn5Xu4GPUIMJ:www.ibrarian.net/navon/paper/Tax_and_Corporate_Social_Responsibility.pdf%3Fpaperid%3D8404118+&cd=7&hl=en&ct=clnk&gl=uk
  39. Aaronson, GAAR Study (2011) http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130321041222/http:/www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/gaar_final_report_111111.pdf.
  40. Lord Neuberger referred more tactfully to Lord Templeman's "characteristically colourful language"; R oao Evans v Attorney General [2015] UKSC 21 at [53].
  41. IRC v Fitzwilliam 67 TC 614 at p.756. Lord Templeman's claim that his attitude is in common with his predecessors is untenable.
  42. 54 TC 101.
  43. Futter v HMRC 81 TC 912 Supreme Court at [135] (emphasis added).
  44. Nourse v Heritage Trustees (15th January 2015) at [15] and [71] accessible www.kessler.co.uk.
  45. Pendragon v HMRC [2015] STC 1825 at [5].
  46. [2015] STC 788 at [59](3) and [65]. But the position will need to be reviewed when the case is final.
  47. See "Artificial" transactions/devices.
  48. Financial Times, 15 Jan 2013. King is co-author of The British Tax System (5th ed, 1990); an excellent book, and a pity it has been allowed to go out of date.
  49. Select Committee on Economic Affairs Report on The Draft Finance Bill 2013 http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201213/ldselect/ldeconaf/139/139.pdf The Select Committee said this was because that "the issue is one concerning the structure of the tax system rather than avoidance involving manipulation of loopholes in the legislation." More analytically, the reason is that these are not examples of tax abuse (in my sense, which I take to be the same as the definition of "abusive" in the GAAR). The GAAR guidance makes this point; see Postpone disposal: GAAR
  50. https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=9rFuhC2ZSEM
  51. In particular: (1) This planning does not give rise to a tax advantage, but to a benefit advantage for the employer; it could not be counteracted by the GAAR. (2) Not every payment to an employee is earnings so it is possible for planning of this kind to fail on the facts. (3) The privacy aspects of secret filming, and the ease with which short clips may misrepresent nuanced positions, seem particularly worrying. For the background, see Johnson, "Tax, Lies and Hypocrisy" (CCH Tax News , Issue 133 25 September 2013); for the law, see the Statutory Maternity Pay (General) Regulations 1986.
  52. Government of India Report of the Taxation Enquiry Commission 1953-54 Vol II para 5
  53. This figure is wrong: it represents a tax rate of 44%. The effective rate of tax should have been 36.11% = £600k tax. Perhaps it is a typo. Perhaps it is irony. Perhaps no-one is intended to take the letter so seriously as to check the figures. If this is an indication of the tax advice given to Mr Osborne, it is rather worrying.
  54. 6 June 2013
  55. This is a danger to which any discussion of morality is subject: see Taylor, A Secular Age (2007) chapter 18.
  56. In 2015 HMRC asked the professional bodies "to take on a greater lead and responsibility in setting and enforcing clear professional standards around the facilitation and promotion of avoidance to protect the reputation of the tax and accountancy profession and to act for the greater public good." See "Tackling tax evasion and avoidance" (the juxtaposition is significant) (2015) para 3.19. https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/413931/Tax_evasion_FINAL__with_covers_and_right_sig_.pdf But the new Professional Conduct in Relation to Taxation 2016) does not go very far in that direction.
  57. For an introduction, see Windsor, "The Ethics of Government Legal Advisers" in Feldman (ed) Law in Politics, Politics in Law (2015).
  58. https://www.sra.org.uk/solicitors/code-of-conduct/guidance/warning-notices/Tax-avoidance---your-duties--Warning-notice.page (September 2017).
  59. See Judicial views.
  60. Unless “avoidance” is intended to mean abuse within the scope of the GAAR.
  61. See Nature of parliamentary debate.
  62. National Audit Office, Tax avoidance: tackling marketed avoidance schemes (2012), para 1.14.
  63. In HMRC's terminology, a tax loss arises from "legal interpretation" when the taxpayer disagrees with HMRC on an issue of tax law.
  64. December 2012 http://www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/sites/default/files/Business_Taxation/Docs/Publications/Reports/TaxGap_3_12_12.pdf. The HMRC paper itself concedes that "There are many sources of potential error and uncertainty in these estimated tax gaps."
  65. IFS, Green Budget 2013 p.297 http://www.ifs.org.uk/budgets/gb2013/gb2013.pdf
  66. IFS, Green Budget 2013 p.290 http://www.ifs.org.uk/budgets/gb2013/gb2013.pdf (footnotes omitted).
  67. ETPF Policy Paper 1 "Who bears the burden of corporate income taxation?" (May 2015) http://www.etpf.org/papers/PP001CorpTax.pdf
  68. Section 1 Constitutional Reform Act 2005.
  69. The other three are democracy, liberty and tolerance, according to the Government "Prevent Strategy", Cm 8092 (2011), para 6.58 where opposition to these values is the definition of "extremism". The point is repeated in the Government "Counter-Extremism Strategy" Cm 9148 (2015): "Extremism is the vocal or active opposition to our fundamental values, including democracy, the rule of law, individual liberty and the mutual respect and tolerance of different faiths and beliefs." https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/97976/prevent-strategy-review.pdf https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/470088/51859_Cm9148_Accessible.pdf
  70. Article 2 TEU provides: "The Union is founded on the values of respect for human dignity, freedom, democracy, equality, the rule of law and respect for human rights..."
  71. Raz, The Authority of Law (2nd ed., 2009), ch. 11 ("The Rule of Law and its Virtue"); Tamanaha, On the Rule of Law (1st ed, 2004); Pech, "The Rule of Law as a Constitutional Principle of the EU" (2009) http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1463242 For the rule of law in a tax context, see Freedman & Vella,"HMRC's Management of the UK Tax System: The Boundaries of Legitimate Discretion" Legal Research paper No 73/2012 (2012) http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2174946##
  72. http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200607/ldselect/ldconst/151/15115.htm
  73. This may be referred to as a thin, formal, procedural or narrow understanding of the rule of law.
  74. The OUCBT paper spells out an implication of this: "The rule of law requires that taxpayers are able to determine the tax consequences of their actions in advance. This can only be done through legislation and not vague notions of fairness."
  75. The boast is an old one. See Blackstone's Commentaries on the Laws of England (1765) vol 2 chap 37: "a country like this, which boasts of being governed in all respects by law and not by will"; and contrast John Adams "A government of laws, and not of men" (1780).
  76. "English Law, UK Courts and UK Legal Services after Brexit The View beyond 2019"
  77. See for instance the problems raised by Lobler Judicial views.
  78. Ransom v Higgs 50 TC 1 at p.94. A similar spirit informed the decision in Vestey v HMRC in 1979; see Charge on transferor.
  79. Reg 21 The Taxes (Base Erosion and Profit Shifting) (Country-by-Country Reporting) Regulations 2016.
  80. http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201516/cmselect/cmstatin/461-ix/46103.htm#inst01
  81. The Committee report was published after the provision came into force.
  82. The argument that reg. 23 is ultra vires is weaker than for reg. 21, because unlike the position for the 2016 regulations, CRS authorises and requires “rules to prevent ... practices intended to circumvent the reporting and due diligence procedures”. See section IX(A)(1). Perhaps the argument is still tenable. Perhaps reg 23 will be read purposefully and somewhat restrictively.
  83. See Residence-property TAAR.
  84. For an example, see Alternative tie-breaker: mutual agreement.
  85. Speech to OECD International Tax Conference, June 2015, as reported http://www.bna.com/beps-troublegloves-off-b17179928708/
  86. See Kessler, Taxation of Non-Residents and Foreign Domiciliaries (3rd ed., 2004).
  87. For one exception, see Forward tax agreements.
  88. Kessler, Taxation of Non-Residents and Foreign Domiciliaries (13th Edn.,2014) Vol 1 para 2.4 (The rule of law).
  89. Response to OTS competitiveness review (May 2014) http://www.citysolicitors.org.uk/attachments/article/105/20140605%20Response%20to%20Office%20of%20Tax%20Simplification%E2%80%99s%20'Competitiveness%20review%20-%20initial%20thoughts%20and%20call%20for%20evidence'.pdf
  90. Hansard, Public Accounts - Minutes of Evidence (6 December 2012) http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201213/cmselect/cmpubacc/788/121206.htm
  91. See Capital loss TAAR
  92. Unallowable Purpose Tests Draft Guidance p.7 gave the number as “over 200” but countless more have been added since 2009. For that guidance, see Motive defence: Introduction.
  93. See Rule of law v. other values.
  94. See Retrospectivity.
  95. See Fairness of 2008 reforms.
  96. http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130129110402/http://cdn.hm-treasury.gov.uk/2011budget_taxavoidance.pdf
  97. R oao APVCO 19 Ltd v HM Treasury [2015] EWCA Civ 648 at [58].
  98. See R oao Huitson v HMRC [2011] STC 1860; R oao APVCO 19 Ltd v HM Treasury [2015] EWCA Civ 648.
  99. For an illuminating discussion of the policy issues in a US context, see Shaviro, When Rules Change, (1st ed, 2000). UK taxpayers may on this point look with envy to the USA, where a norm opposing retrospective legislation is "strongly rooted in popular sentiment, legislative practice, and perhaps even the Constitution as the courts are likely to interpret it" (p.104).
  100. Kessler, Taxation of Non-Residents and Foreign Domiciliaries ( 7th ed., 2008), Vol.1
  101. Typically film schemes, as the names of members of the LLPs concerned are in the public domain.
  102. http://www.theguardian.com/politics/2015/jan/27/peter-mandelson-400000-pound-tax-free-loan The Guardian later amended its website to concede that the loan had been wrongly described as tax-free.
  103. Leading to a gibe in the Spring 2015 budget announcing a policy review deeds of variation. The Guardian rightly asked: what came first – the policy or the joke?
  104. Ironically, the post-tax cost of the payment would have been diminished as it should in principle be deductible in computing taxable profits.
  105. Or was it? "We were not convinced that their actions, in using the letter of tax laws both nationally and internationally to immorally minimise their tax obligations, are defensible." Public Accounts Committee 19th report 2012, para 12. If the convoluted wording was intended to reflect a note of caution, it was lost in the public debate. But I think the obfuscation is just the dialect of politics. The PAC returned to this theme in Ninth Report of Session 2013–14 "Tax Avoidance–Google". A PAC hearing is not, perhaps, well suited to ascertaining the facts; it is not possible to ascertain from this whether the complaint of the PAC is that Google have been conducting successful or unsuccessful tax avoidance.
  106. HMRC, "Taxing the profits of multinational businesses" Issue Briefing, (2012) https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/89030/profits-multinationals.pdf
  107. Ting, "iTax—Apple's International Tax Structure and the Double Non-Taxation Issue" [2014] BTR 40. See Hybrid entities: Introduction
  108. Christian Aid, "Tax for the common good" (2014) http://www.christianaid.org.uk/images/Tax-Morality-Report-J2951.pdf
  109. Maas, Taxation Magazine, 27 February 2013.
  110. See State aid.
  111. HMRC, "GAAR Guidance" (2015) para B5.2 https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/tax-avoidance-general-anti-abuse-rules. The House of Lords Select Committee made the same point
  112. CIOT, "BEPS Action 2: Neutralise the effects of hybrid mismatch arrangements (Recommendations for domestic laws) Response by CIOT, (May 2014) https://www.oecd.org/ctp/aggressive/comments-action-2-hybrid-mismatch-arrangements.pdf
  113. See de Boer & Nouwen (eds) The EU's struggle with Mismatches and Aggressive Tax Planning (2013) para 3.5.2 (General anti-abuse rule).
  114. Ting, "Old wine in a new bottle: Ireland's revised definition of corporate residence and the war on BEPS" [2014] BTR 237.
  115. http://www.oecd.org/ctp/BEPSActionPlan.pdf
  116. Ault, "Some Reflections on the OECD and the Sources of International Tax Principles" (2013) 70(12) Tax Notes International 1195.